The views expressed by contributors are their own and not the view of The Hill

Bureaucrats are profiting off of policy: Only voters can stop them

FILE - An NYSE sign is seen on the floor at the New York Stock Exchange in New York, on June 15, 2022. AP Photo/Seth Wenig, File)

Over the past several months, the Wall Street Journal has been reporting on government officials who profit from their cozy relations with the private businesses they regulate or that otherwise fall within their jurisdictions.

As reported on Dec. 30, most of the officials’ personal financial gains arise from “insider trading,” the presumptively illegal buying or selling of publicly traded stock based on not-yet-public information about pending regulatory intervention to which the market will respond (either positively or negatively) after the action is announced. Bureaucrats and politicians are poster child “insiders” who know what public policies are being devised and can easily predict their effects on company profitability.

In 2021, for example, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation initiated a process to select its primary provider of cloud data storage services. Microsoft was one of the vendors being considered. According to the Journal, “three key officials involved in the discussions, or their family members, owned shares in Microsoft, including the deputy chief information officer who pushed to pick the company.” Lo and behold, Microsoft was chosen and the insiders, along with all other owners, saw an uptick in the company’s stock price, which they could cash in on immediately by selling their shares. 

The Journal reports similar stories from the Export-Import Bank, Federal Communications Commission and U.S. Patent and Trademark Office. Disclosure and conflict-of-interest rules are in place to limit officials’ ability to profit from their regulatory or policymaking powers. 

The story notes, “Federal prosecutors rarely pursue potential violations, however, leaving enforcement mostly to the agencies themselves. The agencies seldom impose punishments for financial conflicts.”


The lack of prosecutorial zeal is explained in part by the difficulty of enforcing laws against insider trading when it is suspected, whether in the private or public sphere. It can be discovered only if the insider buys shares ahead of an anticipated stock price rise or sells ahead of an expected decline. If advance knowledge of a business-friendly policy action causes the price of a company’s stock to rise, penalties are avoided even if insider information triggers a decision not to sell shares previously in the investor’s portfolio.

Conflicts of interest between public officials and the companies within their policy domains are inescapable. As mentioned, the conflicts can be financial if public officials take advantage of information not yet available to other stock-market participants. Or they can materialize in the longer term through the “revolving doors” between government agencies and the private sector. The knowledge and experience necessary to navigate and exploit public-policy processes are valuable to private businesses, who for that reason regularly offer jobs to former public officials as lobbyists, employees of “governmental affairs” departments or well-paid members of their boards of directors.

Economist and Nobel laureate George Stigler launched scholarly literature in 1971 that has since come to be known as the “capture theory” of regulation or a more general interest-group theory of government. The theory features analyses of rules governing over-the-road trucking, stock brokerage, commercial airlines and public electric utilities — most of which originated during the 1930s, and were justified as necessary to protect consumers from the high prices and substandard products thought (usually erroneously) to be coupled with the pursuit of private profits. 

But the evidence adduced by Stigler and the many scholars who followed his lead pointed in the opposite direction: Public regulation results in prices and profits that are higher than they would be under competitive market conditions. Regulation protects producers, not consumers. That conclusion is obvious to anyone who witnessed the consequences of the brief era of deregulation in the late 1970s and early 1980s.

Stigler explained that private businesses obviously have strong financial stakes in public policy processes, while the interests of consumers and taxpayers, who ultimately bear the costs of policy decisions, are much more diffuse. Producers therefore “capture” the policy process through their lobbying efforts, which shape governmental interventions in their own favor. In fact, private business interests often seek regulation to gain protection from competitive market forces.

Public officials also benefit personally from exercising their authority in ways that selectively help or hurt private business interests, like Microsoft. Just-retired Dr. Anthony Fauci made $1.7 million from his governmental position in 2020 alone, which includes profits from investments. Members of Congress profited from selling defense company stocks, many after voting in favor of sending billions in weapons to Ukraine. One can call such behavior corrupt, unethical or crony capitalism, but it is the predictable consequence of the explosive growth in the size and scope of the administrative state over the past century. 

Remedies may be found at the Supreme Court (e.g., West Virginia et al. v. EPA) or in a revival of federalism. Ultimately, however, only the voters can stop political elites’ financial wrongdoing. 

When asked what kind of government had been created in Philadelphia in 1787, Ben Franklin famously replied: “A republic, if you can keep it.”

William F. Shughart II, research director and senior fellow of the Independent Institute (Oakland, Calif.), is J. Fish Smith Professor in Public Choice at Utah State University’s Huntsman School of Business.